image-for-printing

Con Keating: “I’m from the government and I’m here to help”

by

27 Aug 2019

This month Con Keating asks why can’t the authorities get it right
when it comes to pension scheme policy.

Opinion

Web Share

This month Con Keating asks why can’t the authorities get it right
when it comes to pension scheme policy.

This month Con Keating asks why can’t the authorities get it right when it comes to pension scheme policy.

I recently had the pleasure to be one of several academics and practitioners nominating Professor Jane Hutton, a now-suspended whistle-blowing member of the trustee board of the Universities Superannuation Scheme (USS), for the 2019 John Maddox prize.

To quote the Sense about Science website: “The John Maddox Prize for standing up for science rewards an individual who has promoted sound science and evidence on a matter of public interest.”

There is nothing scientific about the valuation process at USS, or for that matter any other UK defined benefit (DB) pension scheme. The choice of discount rates available under currently applicable legislation is a choice among counterfactuals, not an accurate representation of reality.

What is perhaps unusual about USS is that their published narratives are heavily larded with jargon, buzzwords and pseudoscientific trappings; traits shared among many missives from The Pensions Regulator.

There have even been reports in the national press of explicit, and uncorrected, misrepresentation by USS. By contrast, The Pensions Regulator’s narrative is more subtle and nuanced, and in the main contained to its guidance notes.

An illustration is appropriate. Their November 2018 Investment Guidance paper states: “The fundamental purpose of your investment powers is to generate returns in order to enable the scheme to pay the promised benefits as they fall due.” While the Occupational Pensions Schemes (Investment) Regulations require: “Assets held to cover the scheme’s technical provisions must also be invested in a manner appropriate to the nature and duration of the expected future retirement benefits payable under the scheme.”

There is a significant difference here. The primary duty of a trustee is to secure the accrued benefits, and technical provisions are one (overstated) measure of the current value of those liabilities. The transposition from the immediate to the prospective is problematic, particularly so in the case of sponsor insolvency. A company cannot make provision today for situations which eventuate after its insolvency, and if it attempts this, the insolvency administrator should intervene.

This makes the current pursuit of the introduction of long-term funding targets for schemes profoundly problematic; a topic which incidentally provides another example of linguistic contortionism. Funding to self-sufficiency levels has become low-dependency (on the sponsor covenant) in regulator-speak. Make no mistake, this shift of objective will have profound cost implications; a recent study by XPS Pensions estimates the newly required funding at £100bn if weak long-term funding targets (gilts + 75bps) are adopted, and £265bn if strong targets (gilts +25bps) are pursued. Now the section 75 value, the cost of buyout in the bulk annuity market, may define the amount of a scheme’s enforceable claim (after deduction of the level of scheme funding) on the insolvent estate, but this is inequitable to other creditors of the insolvent sponsor. The prospect has resulted in those other creditors taking security, or priority positions in the claims waterfall, and even some of the more extreme pre-pack arrangements.

The weakness of the status of overfunding objectives has been indirectly recognised by the regulator, notably in its recommendation: “Where possible the contingency plans should include legally enforceable rights of recourse.”

Such a course of action would have no effect on the recovery in insolvency, but it would put the scheme in conflict with a solvent but struggling employer. It could also further complicate the matter of dividend policy and corporate strategy. It is hard to see how this is compatible with the regulator’s statutory requirement “to minimise any adverse impact on the sustainable growth of an employer”.

Much of the debate surrounding the USS valuations has centred on their self-sufficiency target, and there has been a scholastic debate of the covenant supporting the scheme. However, by any reckoning, this is strong, though this has not stopped Trinity College, Cambridge, from paying the current section 75 value and withdrawing. Their apparent concern was that they might become the last man standing and face harm to their endowment fund. It would be interesting to know where this ranks alongside other similarly improbable existential threats to that fund, such as actions for restitution from the monasteries, from which it was originally sourced.

The idea of overfunding and low dependence upon the sponsor covenant defies simple reason. The greater the financial strength of the sponsor, the greater the reliance we may place, confidently, upon the sponsor covenant. Indeed, if there is any action warranted, it may be for enhanced terms to members’ employment benefits. For the financially weak, further demands for scheme funding merely exacerbate the situation, and forbearance is likely a far superior strategy.

The Pensions Regulator’s latest foray is into scheme governance. It introduces the expression “savers” for all scheme members. This may be appropriate for defined contribution (DC) arrangements, which are merely tax-advantaged savings schemes, but is it for DB scheme members; they have purchased a pension. The regulator wants to see fewer, better governed schemes. Good governance may make for better DC schemes and benefit their savers, but it is irrelevant to DB scheme members.

There is a staggering admission: “The evidence that the current system doesn’t work for all is stark.” This is after a decade of regulation and supervision by The Pensions Regulator; a decade in which it has presided over, and continues to aid and abet, the demise of DB pensions. It has promoted the incomplete and inadequate alternate of DC schemes. It appears not even to have learned the elementary lesson that hard cases make bad law.

These are governance failings of the first order, but such is their hubris that they feel qualified to set themselves as authorities for the rest of us.

More Articles

Subscribe

Subscribe to Our Newsletter and Magazine

Sign up to the portfolio institutional newsletter to receive a weekly update with our latest features, interviews, ESG content, opinion, roundtables and event invites. Institutional investors also qualify for a free-of-charge magazine subscription.

×